sábado, 31 de agosto de 2013

¿Es la Política la Solución?



Los liberales, con mucha razón, abogan por la reducción del estado en tamaño e influencia. Uno de los principales métodos que tienen para hacerlo es la "solución política": Formar un partido de ideología liberal, acceder al poder y desde allí actuar por la contracción estatal. Debo decir que no estoy en desacuerdo para nada con el fin, sin embargo si lo estoy con ese medio.

Ya vimos que el votar no sirve. Pero aun suponiendo que lo hiciera, podemos decir que la política es un buen medio para reducir el tamaño del estado? Hay, a mi parecer, dos opciones por las cuales se puede explicar la tendencia a crecer por parte del estado:

1) El problema es la gente en el estado: El estado tiende a crecer porque la gente en el estado lo hace crecer. Solución: Si esa gente es reemplazada por otra que haga lo contrario o limitamos legalmente (Constitución) su crecimiento e influencia, el estado disminuiría su tamaño.

2) El problema es el estado: El estado tiende a crecer independientemente de las ideas o la gente en el, debido a su propia esencia y características intrínsecas e inevitables. Solución: Abolir el estado completamente.

Los partidarios de la “solución política” para reducir el estado, necesariamente deben creer en la opción 1), sino no optarían por la política. Desde su punto de vista, bastaría con ganar elecciones, acceder al máximo cargo y desde allí comenzar la reducción progresiva o en su defecto inmediata y de un solo golpe del estado.

Economistas al poder! 

Los economistas en general suelen ser mucho más críticos de la habilidad del gobierno para mejorar la sociedad, o al menos en ciertos aspectos de ella, que los políticos y que otros científicos. No solo la teoría sino además los estudios empíricos demuestran que el estado es mucho más ineficiente que el mercado. Es de esperar que si hay más economistas en el gobierno, este tenderá a decrecer o al menos no aumentar de tamaño. En un estudio reciente Beaulier, Boyes y Mounts (2008) demuestran que esto no ha sido así. Aun cuando ha aumentado su cantidad absoluta y per cápita en la sociedad así como su cantidad dentro del estado, los economistas en el gobierno han sido totalmente incapaces de reducir su crecimiento. Y peor aún, los economistas en el gobierno han ayudado a aumentar su tamaño al producir en la gente actitudes favorables hacia él. “[L]os economistas hacen declaraciones por políticas pro-gobierno. El público recoge las declaraciones de los economistas y al poco tiempo la actitud del público se hace más favorable hacia las políticas pro-gobierno”, explican.

Es claro que aun cuando los más convencidos de que el estado no es la solución están en el poder, no solo el mismo no deja crecer sino que además crean condiciones para aumentar su tamaño. Tratar de “achicar el estado” desde adentro no funciona. Que ocurre?

El incentivo no es todo, pero como ayuda!

Ocurre que la opción 1) es una errónea descripción de lo que en realidad pasa. Aun el más convencido liberal en la presidencia tenderá a no poder reducir el estado debido a que el problema es el sistema, no la gente en él.

1) Seamos realistas, ya vimos que el propio sistema democrático hace que los peores se pongan a la cabeza. Y los peores son los que más arbitrariamente aumentan el tamaño del estado (o prometen hacerlo) y consiguen m
ás apoyo debido a ello. La probabilidad de que un liberal que prometa sinceramente reducir el estado consiga llegar a la presidencia es extremadamente baja. Los incentivos del sistema democrático hacen que los que prometen aumentar los así llamados "beneficios sociales" tiendan a ganar. Imaginen al candidato A diciendo: “vamos a bajar el gasto público, despedir empleados, bajar impuestos, quitar subsidios, quitar salarios mínimos y no les voy a dar nada” VS el candidato B: “vamos a ayudar a los pobres, a hacer que les paguen más en el trabajo con salarios mínimos, a subsidiar el precio de la leche de sus hijos, crear empleos nacionales impidiendo que nos invadan los chinos, jubilarse sin aportar y darles todo lo que pidan”. Quien ganaría? Además para poder ganar, el candidato liberal y su partido deberán hacer alianzas ya sea con otros partidos o con otros sectores, que luego habrá que pagar con aumento de gasto estatal. Pero aun suponiendo que superamos esto, hay problemas. 

2) Los políticos y actores políticos (ya sean abogados, politólogos, sociólogos, economistas, etc.) son humanos. Ante una oportunidad de aumentar sus beneficios propios (estando dentro del gobierno), hasta los más escépticos del intervencionismo estatal tenderán a aprovecharla. Al hacerlo estarán provocando un aumento del tamaño del estado. Sea cual fuere la ideología de la persona, la gente busca usar medios para alcanzar sus fines. Tener más dinero, más prestigio, influencia, un sueño personal, etc. son algunos fines siempre presentes en todos. Dado que todos buscamos lo mismo (usar medios de que disponemos para alcanzar nuestros fines), la respuesta de nuestro comportamiento debemos buscarla en el sistema bajo el cual nos movemos. Sin importar cuan fuertes sean sus ideas de reducir el estado, el presidente liberal se encuentra en un ámbito donde recibe incentivos diferentes y actuará en consecuencia. Debe adaptarse al sistema o su lucha de toda la vida por llegar ahí será en vano. Bajo el sistema estatal los beneficios se privatizan (recaen intégramele sobre una persona o grupo) y los costos se socializan (recaen sobre todos los que pagan), la tendencia a crecer es inevitable. Si hay beneficios durante las expansiones se los lleva todo el político o funcionario, en caso de pérdidas paga el presupuesto. Creer que el presidente liberal no sería corrompido por el poder como cualquier otro hombre, es caer en el supuesto que los propios liberales se han encargado de refutar: que los políticos no son Angeles.

3) No solo el presidente liberal no tiene incentivos para reducir el estado, aun si lo intentara encontraría una gran resistencia. Pensar que, mientras se reduce el estado, los productores que dejan de recibir subsidios y los empleados que pierden su muy segura y artificialmente alta fuente de ingreso no harán nada para evitarlo y lo aceptaran de buena manera, seria caer en la Falacia del Nirvana. Las 7 reglas de la burocracia (español) y la Ley de Parkinson permiten ver los varios métodos por los cuales la burocracia garantiza seguir existiendo y creciendo. La burocracia luchará por mantener su posición ante las amenazas contra su existencia por parte de la máxima autoridad. Se esforzaran por hacer lo que puedan para crear y mantener los problemas que su existencia supuestamente se encarga de solucionar. Los propios políticos, subordinados o no, además no permitirán la destrucción de sus programas y beneficios. El estado no se permitirá hacer el Harakiri.

4) Mientras que la máxima autoridad burocrática del gobierno es baja relativamente en número, los departamentos estatales (que desea eliminar para reducir el estado) son burocracia muy numerosa, con lo cual se están afectando muchos intereses. Eso de por si amenaza la continuidad del proceso de achicamiento estatal o la reducción total ya realizada. El partido liberal gobernante podría ser destituido o perderá la siguiente elección echando por tierra todo lo logrado. La inevitable consecuencia de todo lo anterior es que la reducción vía política del estado debe ser gradual. Una reducción violenta y total solo sacará al partido que lo intente y pondrá a su rival en la ventajosa situación de recomenzar a agrandarlo con todos los beneficios (para el partido rival) de corto plazo que ello trae. El partido liberal estará en la incómoda posición de tener que asegurar su continuidad hasta que se complete la disminución del estado y para lograrlo tendrá que recurrir a las tretas normales de políticos que incluye aumentar el tamaño estatal pues no hay duda que ha perdido mucho apoyo por los beneficios estatales anulados con anterioridad.


Hasta donde conozco, cuando los políticos han tomado medidas para reducir aunque sea un poco el estado, lo han hecho única y exclusivamente porque no tenían otra alternativa. Aun cuando iba en contra de lo que creían, debieron hacerlo pues no había otra opción en casos de hiperinflación o crisis brutales. Una vez más no importó la ideología de la persona sino los incentivos del sistema y las circunstancias.

Como se ve, la "vía política" tiene muchos defectos y hace casi imposible el objetivo de reducir el estado. Así como una monja metida en un prostíbulo no logrará hacer que las prostitutas sean monjas o dejen su "pecaminoso hábito" y se verá obligada a seguir el camino de ellas o abandonar su empresa y escapar; el liberal en el poder no podrá reducir el estado. Sabemos entonces cual NO es el camino. Otras alternativas deben ser tomadas en cuenta.



Bibliografía:

Beaulier, Scott A.; Boyes, William J. y Mounts, William S. (2008), "The Influence of Economists on Public Attitudes Toward Government" Journal: The American Economist, Vol. 52, No. 2, 65-71.

domingo, 25 de agosto de 2013

No, The War Was Not Good



"Lord Keynes" (LK) has two posts, and some others, trying to show something good on World War II. I must say however that I found his attempt highly unconvincing. I will try to show it next.





1)  LK says:
"The sheer absurdity of asserting that “no economic good” of any kind came out of the war is refuted by this point alone. Many people no longer had to experience the grinding poverty of unemployment, and obtained work on the home front when the war started. And they obviously chose that work over being unemployed."
His “one-point refutation” is only valid in the case that there was no other alternative to give jobs to unemployed people than war. But that was not true. 

It is very easy to end unemployment trough all kinds of wasteful projects. Hitler’s military command economy also put an end to German unemployment, even a useless mediocre like Stalin could achieve some kind of "full employment". Can anyone deny the "employment effects" of building big concentration camps? No. But everyone can agree that, in a non-intervened price system, there were other alternative uses to employ those resources. So it is totally wrong to say that "at least" concentration camps "create employment". Concentration camps were just one (very unprofitable and unfeasible in market) project, which to be achieved must employ resources, but there were a lot other profitable projects for those resources in a non-hampered market.  We can apply the same thing to war. 

There is a fact that cannot be denied: Employment to produce things to destroy is very different than employment to produce things to consumers. In both ways you can employ people, but the costs of those employments are different in each situation. People's standard of living will vary in both cases. You can have either a) employment and increasing standards of living or b) employment and lowering and bad standards of living. LK finds some "good" thing in b) only by looking at employment. But b) not only is an inefficient way, it is totally unsustainable because you cannot maintain the destroying policy after everything and every incentive to create have been destroyed. However a) has both qualities: a tendency to efficiency and it is sustainable. 

The “benefit” of employment of the former unemployed people was achieved by creating a loss to those killed/injured or to capital goods and then lowering others' standard of living, not to mention that this kind of employment involves a high risk job for those "employed" in battlefield. You are employing resources to destroy other resources (people killed/injured at front are labor resources lost). But lets assume that bullets, tanks, guns, etc. are produced but no one uses them, so no one is killed. Even here we have a zero-sum game. Resources that could have been devoted to satisfy consumers have been wasted on useless armament, so the “profit” of the jobs created was achieved by the loss of standard of living of everyone (included those employed in armament). In short: There are people employed but there is no enough bread. There is no economic good on all this. 

If a big confrontation were a good remedy for unemployment, we could have obtained a similar result just by hiring unemployed Americans to kill other Americans. Can we deny the employment effects of this? Notice how arbitrary are the possibilities when government "hire" people to do whatever we want if we consider employment as an end, instead of a means to achieve ends. Free-market economists know that work is a means to achieve ends, not an end in itself. If creating jobs is the end, then any end that uses workers is valid, so LK will have to face the reality of admitting that building concentration camps were a good way to create employment. A Hitler's admirer can say that people preferred to work on building gas chambers for Jews rather than "starve in unemployment", and LK will have to accept that statement. 

The only possible answer I think LK can use, is that he is defending a particular end: War against Nazism. However this does not solve the problem, because that is just an arbitrary end. In exactly the same way, Hitler could have said that he was fighting against "malign capitalist exploiter imperialism" and "barbaric communist materialism". As well as Bush could justify his war by saying he was "fighting terrorism" and "avoiding" further attacks on American soil. Since communism and terrorism are as bad as fascism, those wars were justified under LK's criterion. This is not of course a defense of Hitler; it is a criticism of LK's method to justify war: his arbitrariness. Despite the fact that Hitler's was a terrible genocidal totalitarian regime and we can certainly make a case to war him, today there are other bad regimes similar to fascism (North Korea can menace the entire world with nuclear weapons).

It was perfectly possible to "combat" unemployment without destroying resources, without lowering everyone's standard of living, without rationing and putting price controls, without killing people, without destroying capital goods, etc. Had not the government intervened the economy, see Higgs (1997), and labor market, see Gallaway and Vedder (1987), US could have reached the employment of people without the destruction event of war. So there was no merit at all on employing people for war if we compare it with the other possible peaceful market solution.

In focusing in the benefits of one group (those former unemployed now employed) LK is not seeing the group that is victimized and resources lost (those American soldiers killed i.e. less labor, those people forced to reduce their standard of living, those who suffered rationing, inefficient price controls, goods that didn't come to exist because resources are being used to fight war, etc.). It is true that, as Higgs said, some few people benefited from price control. That is the basic fact of a shortage created by maximum price! Some few people will get the product at the artificially lowered price, but there will be a great majority of people that will not. You had, say, 300 people that could buy the milk and 100.000 people that couldn’t. Only by omitting all this (“what is not seen”), one can say that there was something "good" in WWII.

To the extent that war means to deliberately lose real (workers on the front, capital goods, investing iron in tanks instead of cars, etc.) and monetary resources, it does not contribute one iota to prosperity. By concentrating just on employment as the thing “positive” of war, LK has overlooked what was destroyed by that employment and the alternative market method to achieve employment. That destruction, makes his only positive point useless.

There was an alternative way to employ people which could have achieved both 1) not letting the people starve by allowing them to work and at the same time 2) it wouldn't had destroyed wellbeing of every one.  

WWII did lower American's standard of living, as Horwitz and McPhillips (2013) demonstrated, not only from the statistic point of view. Average American did not even think that their standard of living was recovering in those years.

Higgs (1992) also knew it: 
“the deterioration of quality and disappearance from the market of many consumer goods, the full effect of the nonprice rationing of many widely consumed items, and the additional transactions costs borne and other sacrifices made by consumers to get the goods that were available. When one corrects the data to provide a more defensible measure of what happened to real consumer well-being during the war, one finds that it declined… one must recognize that consumers had to contend with other extraordinary welfare-diminishing changes during the war. To get the available goods, millions of people had to move, many of them long distances, to centers of war production… After bearing substantial costs of relocation, the migrants often found themselves crowded into poorer housing. Because of the disincentives created by rent controls, the housing got worse each ear, as landlords reduced or eliminated maintenance and repairs. Transportation, even commuting to work, became difficult for many workers.”
In another place he wrote: 
"Unemployment fell during the war entirely because of the buildup of the armed forces. In 1940, some 4.62 million persons were actually unemployed (the official count of 7.45 million included 2.83 million employed on various government work projects). During the war, the government, by conscription for the most part, drew some 16 million persons into the armed forces at some time; the active-duty force in mid-1945 numbered in excess of 12 million. Voila, civilian unemployment nearly disappeared. But herding the equivalent of 22 percent of the prewar labor force into the armed forces (to eliminate 9.5 percent unemployment) scarcely produced what we are properly entitled to call prosperity."
Higgs  (2004):
"If we take into account only those parts of the wartime capital formation that had value beyond their sheer immediate usefulness in winning the war, and if we give appropriate weight to the significant measurement errors that I have described, then we may conclude with reasonable confidence that, in fact, real capital formation during the first half of the 1940s was not proportionally greater than that during the latter half of the decade; indeed, it was more likely a good deal less. The wartime socialization of investment served a definite purpose in allowing the U.S. military-industrial complex to triumph over the nation’s enemies in World War II. Beyond that, its achievements had little if anything to recommend them."
And also Skousen (1988): 
“Certainly, millions of idle workers were put back to work, but hundreds of thousands died or were wounded on the battlefield. Employment during the war was not particularly easy. The average work week rose 20 percent in manufacturing, construction, and mining, and many key employees, especially engineers, had to work weary 14-hour days, 7 days a week. Taxes increase dramatically and permanently. The standard of living declined during this time, despite higher incomes, as Americans gave up many of the pleasures of life.” 
Even the "orthodox" story demonstrates how restricted and bad the situation of people was. After war they spent their savings on goods that they couldn't get before due to command economy, thus creating a "consumption boom". Higgs (1999a) defies this story, people reduced their real saving rate but they did not dissave. 

It is true that LK recognizes that the people situation’s at war jobs was not good, but his justification is that a bad job is better than no job, ignoring the alternative way to employ people and other costs. 

Real consumption, real private investment (at 55% of its 1941 level) and private output (it was below 1933!) sunk in war years, Murphy (2012). That was certainly not an improvement on standard of living. And remember that millions of people died in war. Putting aside any moral and ethical consideration, that meant a real resource lost because there were less young, productive and healthy workers.

Even Krugman knew that people were living badly: 
"Consumer goods were rationed; people were urged to restrain their spending to make resources available for the war effort."
Yet another cost of war was the massive increase in power of government and decrease civil liberties. Again here is Higgs (1999b)
“World War II witnessed massive violations of human rights in the United States, apart from the involuntary servitude of the military conscripts. Most egregiously, about 112,000 blameless persons of Japanese ancestry, most of them U.S. citizens, were uprooted from their homes and confined in concentration camps without due process of law.” In his obsesion with employment Lk overlooked all this costs. Which is very strange for someone who aparently is social democrat, because these costs are always taken in full account by all members of that left oriented ideology. This are economic issues to the extent that are interventionist meassures."
Not even LK's “advance in technology” favorable argument is true. Actually Mises had answered (Lecture 6 and Human Action) a very similar argument, however it was not about war but about credit expansion.  

If some technological innovation is unprofitable right now, it is because people have more urgent needs right now! At the moment of war people needed other goods or services rather than using resources to develop computer or rocket technology. So that acceleration in technology advance cost satisfactions that were more valued by people. It is not true that that was a improvement. If people were not willing to pay for that technology (either because it was too expense or because it was not discovered a profitable peaceful use yet) on that moment that means that develop that technology on that moment was a wasteful of resources. Let’s see an example to see how bad can be to force acceleration of events. 

You can force your son to work hard and save since he is 10 years old in order for him to purchase his own house in some years. I am sure that he would highly prefer to play and make friends like other kids, but you have “command and control” over him. After some years, maybe at the age of 25, the boy would have paid the full value of a house and LK could say “look! Thanks to command and control of his life, the boy had earned a home at his 25. That is a clear advance over other kids of his same age”. However, in forcing him to work since he was a kid, you have made him waste his childhood in working, and surely he would have preferred to have good friends and play a lot more rather than work. You cannot say that it was a "clear advance" to force him to work since his 10 until his 25 so he has full property of a house. As in Mises' railroad example, the boy could have owned the house 20 years later (at his 45) without squandered his childhood, but because of command and control of his father he had the “crisis” and trauma of not having had a good childhood. Even if the kid had his own house, we cannot say his father improved his life through forcing him to get his home sooner. In the same way we cannot say that "forced" acceleration in technology advance in WWII has necessarily “improved” American's life, because we would be forgetting all the things consumers could not afford in order to develop by force the technology on war years.

War costs manpower, the lose of capital goods and other real resources, reduction in standard of living, freedoms of people and is a very risky adventure. Computers, radar, nuclear power, rockets and internet would have existed with or without war. The only possible “merit” of war, was accelerating by force its appearance. However the costs of that acceleration were far greater than benefits of having them at an earlier date. What is seen is the computer, rockets, jet, etc. that maybe would not have been developed so soon, LK completly fails to notice what is not seen. So LK cannot affirm that that was an “improvement”. This is not a moralistic critique; costs by far surpassed benefits from people’s and economic point of view. Maybe from political and military point of view war was a "success", but not from society's. Notice that I’m not saying that LK advocates war, what I am saying is that the things that he considers “good” about it, had a lot of higher unseen costs, so they cannot be seen as a net good result. 

And about his assertion that there were a lot of malinvestments after war, yes there were. However "Lord Keynes" must know that, from Austrian point of view, produced capital goods have different degree of convertibility. Some capital goods can be saved from government’s made disaster by entrepreneurs. One example is Aristotle Onassis. When war ended and there were a lot of useless Liberty ships, he had the entrepreneurial ability to anticipate a future increase in naval commerce and bought some of those ships. Because of that, he made great part of his fortune. And again it must be remembered that when we talk about past malinvestments, savings also helped! Far from “refute” Austrian theory, this only reinforce the Austrian story. 

In short. All Austrians know very well that any amount unemployment can be easily removed by government just by building a lot of pyramids. What they also know is that 1) It is unnecessary, because employment could have also been achieved by non-intervened wages (this does not mean "lowering ALL wages" like some ignorants think) 2) Totally inefficient, as the lowering in standard of living of Americans in WWII demonstrated 3) Unsustainable. 

One last thing about unemployment numbers of the Great Depression. Darby's method was completely refuted by Kesselman and Savin (1978) and severely criticized by Gordon (1976). So there is no discussion on unemployment figures here because Darby completely failed.

2) LK continues:
"Secondly, the war allowed the accumulation of savings and money income. The point overlooked by Higgs is that this also allowed both business and consumers to finally complete the process of deleveraging and paying down private debt to a low level. That is a fundamental point: the debt deflationary drag on the US economy was eliminated during the war, as we can see in this graph (in the “private debt” line)."
Austrians before that paper of Higgs knew very well the role of that particular kind of “forced saving” during war. Actually that was in full conformance with Austrian theory, as Skousen (1988) said:
"[I] suggest that the World War II economic boom was in large part the result of a third major factor, often ignored by most economists. This factor is the unprecedented rise in personal and business saving rates during 1941-45. The spectacular rise in private savings provided the billions of dollars necessary to support the war,… Although several variables (including government spending, monetary inflation, and tax rates) changed during World War II, it is remarkable how economic trends followed this Austrian scenario… According to Austrian theory, increased savings and lower interest rates will, other things being equal, precipitate an expansion of raw commodities and capital-intensive industries."
What Austrians also knew, was that 1946 was not thanks to Keynesianism, Vedder and Gallaway (1991)
“In short, rather than "pent-up demand" preventing a depression, the evidence is more consistent with a distinctly non-Keynesian interpretation: A downward adjustment in labor supply and real wages, accompanied by a more responsible (non-deficit) fiscal policy, served to stimulate investment and consumption spending. Relative price adjustments brought about what Keyensians perceived to be an increase in aggregate demand, rather than the other way around… The evidence shows that aggregate demand rose too little and too late to explain the low unemployment that prevailed in the first two years after V-J day, the period in which demobilization was completed. What did happen was that labor markets, partially con- strained by non-price factors in the wartime period, were allowed to function in a manner that prevented a serious decline. Labor supply abruptly fell, but in addition real wages, adjusted for productivity change, also fell, preventing a massive rise in unemployment. ”
I think that it's unnecessary to say that Austrians also know very well that deleveraging is good for economy.

 3)  LK then says:
"Thirdly, the war fundamentally shifted business expectations from being highly pessimistic to a strong optimism that emerged after the conflict ended."
As explained before, ("forced") savings played a big role. But if LK thinks that “optimistic” expectations helped to revive private investment, then he must accept Higgs’ regime uncertainty explanation on how businessmen's expectations were crushed by Roosevelt's interventionism. 

Finally let’s be fair. I have seen LK in comment sections of a lot of blogs and I am reading some of his own posts. LK accuses others on “citing ad nauseam” Higgs, and maybe he is right. However by using his own criterion for example I can accuse him of citing ad nauseam Sraffa on every single discussion about ABCT in every place. 

Conclusion    

It is true that WWII lowered enormously unemployment and created a boom, nobody has ever denied that. However it is not true that this was a “good” thing about war, if we take in account that there was an alternative better method to employ people. And that alternative method was by far more efficient and sustainable than war.  Besides there were a lot of costs that are not taken into account when we talk about the "benefits" of war.

There was nothing we can call "good" about WWII. The only good war was this one...



 

Bibliography

Gallaway, Lowell and Vedder, Richard K. (1987) "Wages, Prices, and Employment: Von Mises and the Progressives". Journal: The Review of Austrian Economics, Vol. 1, No. 1.

Gallaway, Lowell and Vedder, Richard K. (1991) “The Great Depression of 1946”. Journal: The Review of Austrian Economics, Vol. 5, No. 2.

Gordon, Robert J. (1976) "Recent developments in the theory of inflation and unemployment". Journal: Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 2, No. 2. Northwestern University, Evanston, IL , U.S.A.

Higgs, Robert. (1992) "Wartime Prosperity? A Reassessment of the U.S. Economy in the 1940s". Journal: The Journal of Economic History.

Higgs, Robert. (1997) "Regime Uncertainty: Why the Great Depression Lasted So Long and Why Prosperity Resumed after the War". Journal: The Independent Review, Vol. 1, No. 4.

Higgs, Robert. (1999a) "From Central Planning to the Market: The American Transition, 1945-1947". Journal: The Journal of Economic History, Vol. 59, No. 3. Cambridge University Press.  

Higgs, Robert. (1999b) "How War Amplified Federal Power in the Twentieth Century". The Freeman.

Higgs, Robert. (2004) “Wartime Socialization of Investment: A Reassessment of U.S. Capital Formation in the 1940s”. Journal: The Journal of Economic History, Vol. 64, No. 02.

Horwitz, Steven and McPhillips, Michael J. (2013) “The Reality of the Wartime Economy: More Historical Evidence on Whether World War II Ended the Great Depression”. Journal: The Independent Review, Vol. 17, No. 3.

Kesselman, Jonathan R. and Savin, Eugene N. (1978) "Three-and-a-Half Million Workers Never Were Lost." Journal: Economic Inquiry 16. Oxford University Press, UK. 

Murphy, Robert P. (2012) "The Myth of Wartime Prosperity". The American Conservative.

Skousen, Mark. (1988) “Saving the Depression: A New Look at World War II”. Journal: The Review of Austrian Economics, Vol. 2, No. 1.

viernes, 23 de agosto de 2013

“Econo-Mia [y Tuya]” Cumple 10.000!!!


(Bueno, en realidad 11.000 porque dejé 1.000 visitas de margen debido a sitios spam tipo blogsrating.pw, vampirestat.com, topblogstories.com, etc.)

Hace casi un año publicaba la primera entrada de este blog (se nota que era novato...). Debo admitir que ni en mis sueños más optimistas pensé que llegaría a esta suma en solo un año ni que tendría lectores de lugares del planeta tan distantes. De hecho, pensaba que a esta altura estaría festejando los primeros 1.000!

Thanks to all my english-speaker readers that also contributed to this celebration!
 
Muchas gracias a todos los lectores que hicieron que “Econo-Mia [y Tuya]” lograra 10.000 visitas!

lunes, 19 de agosto de 2013

Crecí-miento: El Mito del "Mayor Crecimiento de la Historia"


Una y otra vez el gobierno y sus defensores repiten, con sus matices, el mismo eslogan que en sus diferentes formas suena más o menos así: "Hoy el país (Argentina) está viviendo el mayor crecimiento de toda su historia".

Una frase muy fuerte y potente que impresionaría a cualquiera pero que, sin embargo, está lejos de ser verdad, al menos con los hechos de que disponemos. Vamos a desmontar ese mito usando datos de la CEPAL (1958), Cortés Conde (2009), Ferreres (2010) y Martínez (1999).

Antes que nada y aguantando la respiración por un momento, observemos estos 35 segundos de propaganda proselitista.


La frase clave es:
"Una Argentina que ha generado el crecimiento del producto bruto más importante de sus 200 años de historia."
No solo es "exagerada" como dicen los muchachos de Chequeado.com, es totalmente falsa!!!

Si vamos a hablar de "200 años" hay que saber cuánto era el PBI desde 1810. Como en esa época claramente no existían las cuentas nacionales (las mismas solo se extendieron internacionalmente luego de la II Guerra Mundial y la última actualización importante de acuerdo con el sistema de la ONU fue en 1993), lo único que podemos hacer son estimaciones de esas magnitudes. Algunos de los mejores investigadores que las hicieron de forma muy documentada para antes del Siglo XX son Cortés Conde (2009) y especialmente Ferreres (2010) que llega hasta 1810. Con lo cual cualquier afirmación deberá basarse en sus trabajos. 

Similar a lo que hizo Batalla en su excelente post, me encargué de preparar el siguiente cuadro. En él está reflejado el crecimiento acumulado para diferentes periodos de acuerdo a diferentes fuentes, siempre tomando en cuenta expansiones anuales de PBI real consecutivas hasta el momento de una contracción. A diferencia de Batalla, yo no tomo en cuenta los años que dura la expansión sino solo el porcentaje positivo acumulado. Hay que notar que he decidido llegar hasta 2009 porque en ese año según las cifras oficiales el PBI creció solo 0.85%, mientras que todos los analistas privados estiman que el mismo cayó. Creo que nadie serio puede argumentar que el producto no cayó en 2009. Por lo tanto el ciclo expansivo consecutivo del kirchnerismo tuvo su fin en ese año. Pintado en azul se encuentra el crecimiento acumulado K tomando cifras oficiales.

Ranking de crecimiento acumulado del PBI real por periodo según diferentes autores

El único cuya serie de PBI real se remonta hasta 1810 es la de Ferreres (2010), por lo que solo basándonos en él podemos ver si es cierto el discurso del gobierno. Obviamente se observa que la afirmación de Kirchner es falsa. Ni siquiera si tomamos en cuenta el PBI oficial, que exagera el crecimiento de 2008 y además hace que la caída de 2009 se convierta en un crecimiento ínfimo, el periodo 2003-2009 es el "más importante". Se encuentra en un cómodo 7mo. lugar detrás de 1964-74. No solo no es el crecimiento más importante de los últimos 200 años, sino que ni siquiera entraría en un "Top Five".

La serie de Cortés Conde (2009) deja al crecimiento oficial en el cuarto lugar y tengamos en cuenta que solo llega hasta 1935. Si cubriera más años del Siglo XX, la expansión K estaría aún más abajo.

No debería extrañar a nadie que el periodo más importante de crecimiento acumulado haya sido a partir de 1880 con la "Gran Expansión Industrial Argentina".

Llegamos ahora hasta la serie cuya seriedad y certeza no puede (creo!) ser cuestionada por ningún admirador del gobierno: La CEPAL (1958). La misma abarca la mitad del Siglo XX y deja al "glorioso" periodo K en un tercer lugar, vamos avanzando! Pero una vez más hay que aclarar que, debido a que fue publicada en 1958, no toma en cuenta otros años de gran expansión como los 60's.

Finalmente la serie más corta de todas: La del BCRA (1975) cuyos datos los obtuve de Martínez (1999). Al abarcar solo 24 años podemos esperar que el crecimiento K finalmente este en el tan ansiado primer lugar... pero sorpresa! El boom kirchnerista fue opacado por la expansión de los 60's y principio de los 70's.

Todo lo anterior descontando que varias de las expansiones que superan la Era K no venían de una caída tan profunda como la de 2002 (con lo cual había menos "efecto rebote") ni tenían términos de intercambio tan favorables.

Como se observa, este es solo un caso más de los cientos en que el relato kirchnerista no soporta la realidad.




Bibliografía


Cortés Conde, Roberto. (2009) The Political Economy of Argentina in the Twentieth Century. New York: Cambridge University Press. 

Ferreres, Orlando J. (2010) Dos Siglos de Economía Argentina 1810-2010. Edición Bicentenario. El Ateneo y Fundación Norte y Sur, Buenos Aires.

Martínez, Ricardo G. (1999) “Recopilación de Series Históricas del Producto y del Ingreso”. CEPAL, Buenos Aires.
 
Naciones Unidas, CEPAL. (1958) El Desarrollo Económico de la Argentina. Anexo: Algunos Estudios Especiales y Estadísticas Macroeconómicas Preparados para el Informe. Naciones Unidas: Consejo Económico y Social. CEPAL, Chile.